ツイッター paper.li Vol.14

All the below links are in English.

弊社ツイッターアカウントの一つ @WSjp_insight のRTにより、元々取り上げておられたオランダの関係機関に特に喜んで頂けたと思われ、また paper.li 掲載された記事1件を貼っておきます。

These economies have the best infrastructure | @wef @hollandtrade @NLEnterprise

cf.
https://twitter.com/dutchdailynews/status/806476128382754817
https://twitter.com/NLEnterprise/status/806476638758244352
https://twitter.com/NLEnterprise/status/806476614200659968
https://twitter.com/hollandtrade/status/806475994836168705

New Zealand ニュージーランド Vol.4

(The below links are in English.)

1. Financial stability risks from housing market cycles (19/07/2016) | Michael Thornley @ReserveBankofNZ(住宅市場の循環による金融安定性のリスク)の本文抜粋です。

1 Introduction …the global financial crisis (GFC)…

2 Housing market boom-bust cycles 及び 3 Direct exposure of the financial system to the housing market 
では、US、UK等、NZに特化しない国際的な事象につき説明されています。

4 Indirect exposure of the financial system to the housing market
Impact on household consumption(家計消費への影響)
There is substantial literature on how household consumption responds to changes in housing wealth. Some theories argue that consumption should be completely unresponsive to changes in house prices as (i) households can borrow against their future income to support consumption and (ii) houses are a consumption good in their own right,
so house price declines would not affect a home-owner’s net wealth if they coincide with a decline in rental prices.
These arguments, however, depend on households having standard preferences, rational asset prices and no credit market frictions. Empirical evidence suggests that, in practice, household consumption is affected by house prices. One study finds that during the GFC, US households on average reduced their consumption by $540 for every $10,000 decline in the value of their home
Recent research also suggests that the responsiveness of household consumption to house prices is affected by the size and distribution of household debt. This is particularly noteworthy, as household debt-to-disposable income ratios have grown substantially in many advanced economies since the turn of this century (figure 6). In New Zealand, this growth was driven mainly by mortgage debt…
nz4-fig6
…countries with high aggregate household debt to disposable income ratios in 2007 suffered larger reductions in consumption in 2007-12, when controlling for other factors. …when public and corporate debt increase above certain thresholds it is bad for GDP growth. A negative relationship between household debt (above 85 percent of GDP) and future growth is found but the estimate is extremely imprecise.
… There are broadly two reasons why highly indebted households might reduce consumption more than other households when facing income or housing wealth shocks. First, income and wealth shocks may cause households to increase precautionary savings in response to lower expectations for future income, and this response may be larger for more highly indebted households (the ‘precautionary savings channel’). Second, income and wealth shocks may cause lenders to disproportionately restrict lending to highly indebted households in response to lower expectations for future income and concerns about the collateral value of their homes (the ‘credit availability channel’). …

Impact on sectors related to the housing market(住宅市場関連分野への影響)
… A housing market downturn can affect the construction industry, for example, by reducing demand for new property, reducing the value of the portfolio of land they hold awaiting future construction or causing projects to be written off due to lack of funding. This was demonstrated in Ireland and Spain in the GFC, when a pre-crisis boom in construction collapsed and caused significant losses for the local banking systems. The collapse of the domestic housing markets resulted in severe losses for the financial system, forced government bail-outs (which in Ireland amounted to around 40 percent of GDP) and, ultimately, forced the governments to seek financial support from international agencies…
A housing downturn could also depress the commercial property market by reducing the value of land and property that leveraged commercial property developers have used as collateral to borrow against, threatening their solvency or future borrowing capacity. A relatively large proportion of bank losses in past financial crises are estimated to have come from loans to the commercial property sector… For example, prior to the Nordic and Japanese financial crises in the early 1990s, there was rapid growth in commercial property prices and construction, following a property boom fuelled by financial liberalisation. Significant loan losses were incurred when rising interest rates and slowing economic activity triggered a sharp fall in commercial property prices.

5 Summary and implications for financial stability in New Zealand
A housing market downturn can cause ‘direct losses’ for banks on mortgage lending, with losses typically being larger on mortgages to highly levered borrowers. It can also contribute to ‘indirect losses’ on lending to sectors related to the housing market, such as the construction and commercial property sectors, and more generally, by affecting household consumption and economic activity.

5.1 Assessment of housing market risks in New Zealand
The Reserve Bank has reason to be wary of these risks in New Zealand. New Zealand house prices have displayed a degree of cyclicality in recent years (figure 7) and although we have not seen a major decline in prices since the early 1980s, many other advanced economies have experienced sharp and significant declines in house prices, particularly during the GFC. In addition, New Zealand banks’ exposure to the housing market has increased in the past two decades: in aggregate, mortgage lending comprised less than 40 percent of banks’ overall lending portfolio in 1994 and has risen to around 52 percent today.
nz4-fig78
House prices in New Zealand were among the fastest growing in advanced economies last year and have grown faster relative to incomes than in most advanced economies in the five years after 2010 (figure 8). The house price to income ratio in Auckland rose to 9 in Q1 2016, high internationally and up significantly from 6 in 2012.
There are also signs that a significant proportion of new mortgage lending in New Zealand is highly levered. Currently, around 40 percent of residential mortgages are issued at more than five times the borrower’s gross annual income. Anecdotally, banks were much less willing to write mortgage loans this large relative to income in the aftermath of the GFC and also required substantial deposits. This cyclicality of mortgage supply could exacerbate cyclicality in the housing market, as a price-credit loop can fuel dramatic escalations in house prices and amplify sharp falls in prices.
Property investors may also amplify housing market cycles as they are more likely than owner-occupiers to purchase houses during a housing boom and sell during a housing crash, as their decisions are driven by profit-seeking behaviour. This is a risk in Auckland, where nearly half of recent house sales have been to investors.
It is difficult to estimate the amount house prices could decline in a housing market downturn and the subsequent losses the financial system could face. While the New Zealand market does not currently exhibit the moral hazard and weak mortgage underwriting standards exhibited in the US and Ireland prior to the GFC, there are still risks from high LVR and high DTI mortgages.
Changes in the size and distribution of household debt may have increased the financial stability risk from a housing downturn in recent years. Since 2000 the level of household debt-to-GDP has increased significantly in New Zealand, as in other advanced economies (figure 6). And of the households that took out new mortgages in the period 2011-13, a larger proportion did so at high LVR (>80%) and DTI multiples (>4), than in the period 2008-10 …these households are likely to reduce their consumption by more than other households in a house price crash.
…banks may significantly reduce their lending in an economic downturn, so highly indebted households may face tighter credit constraints and place a further drag on consumption.

5.2 Policy frameworks to mitigate housing market risks in New Zealand
One of the primary responsibilities of the Reserve Bank is to promote the maintenance of a sound and efficient financial system. The Reserve Bank has a number of policy options to help maintain financial stability. Microprudential policies, which include bank capital and liquidity regulations, promote the soundness and resilience of individual financial institutions, and therefore the integrity of the financial system as a whole.
Macroprudential policies, which include countercyclical capital buffers and temporary LVR restrictions, promote greater financial stability by (a) building additional financial system resilience during periods of rapid credit growth and rising leverage or abundant liquidity, and (b) dampening excessive growth in credit and asset prices. Therefore, the Reserve Bank can use both microprudential and macroprudential policies to mitigate the risk that housing market vulnerabilities pose to New Zealand’s financial system stability and the broader economy.
The financial system’s first line of defence against a housing market downturn is the loss-absorbing capital it holds against expected and unexpected losses on its mortgage lending and other exposures. To enhance the resilience of this defence, the Reserve Bank monitors banks’ provisioning against expected losses and requires banks to hold buffers of capital against unexpected losses, where the size of the buffer is determined by the size and riskiness of the lending. These capital requirements bolster the resilience of individual financial firms, even in a severe downturn, but in some circumstances they may not be sufficient to preserve the stability of the financial system as a whole. As the GFC demonstrated, the actions of individual banks, investors, firms and households are interconnected and can collectively result in financial system losses that are exceptional and unexpected when assessed from the perspective of an individual financial institution e.g. due to credit crunches or falls in consumption or investment.
… Stress test results are, however, subject to inherent uncertainty over the scenarios against which banks are tested and the approach to modelling losses on the basis of the given scenarios. Furthermore, the stress test assessed the resilience of banks to a ‘static’ scenario and do not take account of the on-going interaction between the macroeconomic and macro-financial elements of the scenarios and banks’ response to them. These second order effects can themselves be a threat to financial stability and can fall within the scope of the Reserve Bank’s macro-prudential policy instruments. In particular…discussed in section 4.
A second line of defence to protect the financial system from a housing market downturn is to reduce the potential scale of the downturn itself by using borrower-based macroprudential tools such as LVR and DTI limits. These measures may also temporarily reduce the probability of a housing downturn, although that is often not the primary objective.
In recent years, the national authorities of many countries, including the Reserve Bank, have taken some form of proactive action to mitigate the build-up of financial stability risks from their domestic housing market. In 2013, the Reserve Bank introduced a 10 percent speed limit on mortgage lending with an LVR of greater than 80 percent, which has helped reduce the stock of high LVR mortgages from 21 percent to 12 percent (figure 9). In addition, the Reserve Bank introduced a speed limit on high LVR investor mortgages in Auckland in November 2015 which appears to have moderated the nationwide share of investor lending at LVRs greater than 70 percent.
nz4-fig910
In many cases, national authorities use more than one macroprudential tool to tackle risks from the housing market. For example, it is common for caps on LVR and DTI to be applied together… The rationale for this approach is that in theory the macroprudential tools are complementary as they can tackle the same risks from various angles. For example, the LVR policy in New Zealand has helped to reduce the stock of risky high-LVR lending, but risks in the housing market remain, as a significant amount of New Zealand’s new residential mortgage lending, particularly to investors, is at high DTI multiples (figure 10).

2. Household debt (9/9/2016) | @ReserveBankofNZ(家計負債)
In the 20 years to 2011, total housing and consumer loan debt increased around six-fold in dollar terms. As a ratio of household disposable income, the percentage at June 2011 of 147% is about two and a half times that of 58% at March 1991. Through the mid-2000s, household debt grew strongly, at an average annual rate of over 14% in the five years to June 2007. The rate of growth slowed sharply from 2007, averaging well under 4% per annum in the four years to June 2011. …

ツイッター paper.li Vol.13

All the below links are in English.

弊社ツイッターアカウントの一つ @WSjp_insight のRTによる paper.li 掲載記事6件を貼っておきます。

Boston’s Christmas Tree Tradition Rooted In A Canadian Thank You (w Audio) | @ebherwick3 @NPR

B.C. and Alaska strengthen commitment to protect shared environment | @BCGovnews

Howe bridge unaffected by Trump election, Canada says | @leonardnfleming,@HollyPFournier @detroitnews

Gordie Howe International Bridge project spans new horizons | @INFC_eng

Canada pledges to phase out traditional coal power by 2030 | @josh_wingrove @StarTribune

Line 3 Replacement Project | @NRCan

All of these were adopted by @GilTheJenius. Thank you.

ツイッター paper.li Vol.12

All the below links are in English.

弊社ツイッターアカウントの一つ @WSjp_insight のRTによる paper.li 掲載記事4件を貼っておきます。

Dutch coast ‘superstorm’ proof for the next 50 years | @HollandWater

Donald Trump’s @nytimes Interview: Full Transcript | @liamstack,@Jonesieman,@KarenWorkman,@TimHerrera (@deanbaquet,@maggieNYT,@shearm,@mikiebarb,@DouthatNYT,@tomfriedman @BumillerNYT,@JBennet,@juliehdavis,@grynbaum,@maureendowd,@SuccessMatters)

Trump understands what many miss: people don’t make decisions based on facts – How can we make facts matter? Research in psychology and political science offers a little hope. | @juliaoftoronto,@B_resnick @voxdotcom

NEW ACTIVE PACKAGING TO REDUCE FOOD WASTE: 700,000 tons of food waste is thrown away in Denmark each year, food which could have been eaten. This is why scientists are working on developing a new active packaging that prolongs the shelf life for fresh fruit and vegetables by slowing down decomposition. | @stateofgreendk @MFVMin

“The Creation and Destruction of Value” 価値の創造と破壊 Vol.14

(All the below links are in English.)

Vol.14 パワーポリティクスの重要性(第5章-4)

 多くの米国人以外の者にとって本能と逆で苛々するのは、米国の大企業が崩壊したのに何故米国が金融の安全避難地になるのか、ということである。2007年以前には、米国のビジネス周期の不安定さは1980年代初期以来低くなってきた、と一部で言われていた。しかし、この不安定さが無くなるということは、予防的な貯蓄集めのインセンティブを下げ、米国のとりわけ個人貯蓄率を下げ、結果、海外からの資本流入を集めることとなった。
 望まれたのは、金融危機が防衛予算削減をも含む財政的対応でもあったが、実際には外国資本流入に頼り続けていた。それゆえ、流入がただ滞っただけでも、米国の不安定化は始まり、外国にとって米国の安定化に寄与する政治的利益は下がり、更なる流出が起こることとなる。
 2009年初期に金融危機が悪化した際には、米国国債保有の評価額が下げられないよう或いは奪われないよう、中国首脳は保証を要求し始めた。暗に、そのような保証が無ければ、米国国債は中国にとって将来魅力的で無くなる、と脅していたのである。

参考
THE “GREAT MODERATION” AND THE US EXTERNAL IMBALANCE (PDF) | Fabrizio Perri & Alessandra Fogli @NBER
National Data – GDP & Personal Income | BEA @CommerceGov
INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL INTERMEDIATION: DEFICITS BENIGN AND MALIGNANT – ESSAYS IN INTERNATIONAL FINANCE No. 68, June 1968 (PDF) | GEORGE N. HALM @princetonecon
China, Debt, and Influence | Conn Carroll @DailySignal

U.S.A. アメリカ Vol.12(Policy Changes Vol.2 ー 政策変更)

All the below links are in English.

以下弊社ページ(全て英語)は、標記につき取り急ぎ関係記事の一部を抜粋したものです。
各回、複数の分類に入り得る記事があります。
今後も、原則として、弊社英語サイトにて動向を追う等して参ります。

Vol.12 貿易

Vol.11 安全保障

Vol.10 研究開発

Vol.9 観光、航空等

Vol.8 インフラ

Vol.7 外交、国際政治

Vol.6 税制

Vol.5 エネルギー

Vol.4 規制撤廃

Vol.3 移民

Vol.2 雇用

Vol.1 ヘルスケア

ツイッター paper.li Vol.11

All the below links are in English.

弊社ツイッターアカウントの一つ @WSjp_insight のRTによる paper.li 掲載記事4件を貼っておきます。

More on Trade Policy Preferences: The Harvard-Politico Poll | Stephan Haggard @PIIE

Tourism industry needs more investment | @LincolnUniNZ

Old and in the way? Aging workers and generational battle lines in the workplace (Podcast) | @upclosepodcast,@unimelb (Prof Mia Rönnmar @lunduniversity)

Atlantic City Employment Continues to Decline Says Stockton’s South Jersey Economic Review | @Stockton_edu @HughesCenter,@Stockton_BUSN

U.S.A. アメリカ Vol.11(Policy Changes under Trump Administration ー トランプ共和党新政権での政策変更)

(All the below links are in English.)

日本時間9日午後3時(アメリカ東部標準時9日午前1時 1am 11/9 EST)少し前の時点で開票が終了しておらず優勢陣営の勝利宣言もまだ確認できていませんし、何処かで票の数え直し等起こるのかもしれませんが、このまま行けば、アメリカ大統領選挙はドナルド・トランプ共和党大統領候補の当選に終わりそうです。何度目かの揺れ戻しが再び投票終了までにあったのか、隠れトランプ支持や世間の予定調和的発想の多さなども含めてそもそも世論調査等が的を得ていないのか(参照:worldsolutions.work “US Presidential Election 2016 Vol.7 (polls up to early morning 11/7)”)、今後議論されるでしょうが、選挙ですから毎度何が起きるか分かりません。
部外者かつ外国人が言うのは求められていませんが敢えて言うなら、クリントン候補はよく頑張ったと感じています。病に倒れた後である、民主党政権8年の後である、夫が既に8年間大統領を務めた後である、教育機関とは逆に政界での女性の立場はアメリカでは強くない、SNS等により国民の世俗化が進む中でエリート過ぎる、真偽を問わずスタッフ等に関する様々なスキャンダルがあった、などでしょうか。
なお、連邦上院及び下院でもそれぞれ共和党が過半数を取りそうです。

アメリカでは内閣総辞職や解散総選挙が無いので、まずは4年間このトランプ共和党新政権が続きます。日米同盟の下、我が国は新政権と上手く付き合っていくことになります。

もちろん政権の今後を正確に見通せる人は存在しませんし、大統領選挙中のトランプ新大統領(2017年1月20日、就任式・政権発足予定)の発言や政策は細部不透明なものが少なくなかったため主張していた政策が今後変わり得ますが、少なくとも US Presidential Election 2016 Vol.3 (Mr. Donald Trump’s policies) から今後の政策変更を感じることはできます。

日本にとって緊喫の課題となるTPPや在日米軍については今後の様々な動きを注視するとして、
環境規制も含めた経済コストを上げてしまっている規制を撤廃する規制政策(Regulations Read Donald J. Trump’s Plan To Put an End to Burdensome Regulations は無くなっているので今後新たに発表されるのでしょう)、
合法移民の経済状態を守りつつアメリカ国民の雇用等を優先し不法移民を取り締まる移民政策(Immigration Read More on Donald J. Trump’s 10 Point Plan to Put America First も無くなっているので今後新たに発表されるのでしょう)、
全国平均で25%も保険料が上がってしまっているオバマケアを廃止し Health Savings Accounts (HSAs) を導入する医療保険政策(Health Care 添付されている HCReformPaper.pdf も要参照)、
清潔な空気や水を維持しながらエネルギー分野での雇用増大などを図るエネルギー政策(Energy Read Donald J. Trump’s 100-Day Action Plan も無くなっているので今後新たに発表されるのでしょう)、
2500万人の雇用を創出する経済政策(Economy Read Donald J. Trump’s Plan to Create 25 Million Jobs も無くなっているので今後新たに発表されるのでしょう)、
と相互に関連する国内経済政策の方針部分を見るだけでも、今後アメリカ国内の政策も雰囲気も変わって行き、日本も含めた対外政策や国際情勢にも当然影響してくるはずです。
日本政府や日本企業、日本国民においても、日々、様々な分析や対応などが必要になります。

U.S.A. アメリカ Vol.10(U.S. Senate & House ー 連邦議会上院及び下院)

(All the below links are in English.)

選挙なので様々ある中でも10/28のFBI捜査再開がクリントン候補への逆風となったものの、不起訴とすることを再捜査により決定した旨の11/6のFBI発表は、大統領選挙については逆風を短期間で収束させつつある、と各種世論調査から読むことはできます(参照:連邦議会上下両院議員選挙及び知事選挙も含めて、worldsolutions.work “US Presidential Election 2016 Vol.7 (polls up to early morning 11/7)”)。
アメリカでも、捜査するしない・起訴するしないが原則検察官等に委ねられているのは、日本の刑事訴訟法189条2項(犯罪があると思料し捜査を開始)・248条(起訴便宜主義)などと大筋同様(例:Information Network for Mutual Assistance in Criminal Matters and ExtraditionThe Theory Of Prosecutorial Discretion In Federal Law: Origins And Developments (PDF) | Rebecca Krauss (@YaleLawSch) @SetonHallLaw 4頁目)のようですから、新たな証拠が見つかるなど無い限り本件の蒸し返しは今後無い、ということでしょうか。
尤も、11/5までに4000万人を超え既に4年前の前回を上回っている期日前投票、更には連邦議会選挙や知事選挙にも影響は無かったと言い切るのは少なくとも感覚的には難しいでしょう。

その連邦議会上院及び下院の政策関連権限、そしてその権限に基づき今後の政策方向性に大きく作用する上下両院の議席予測につき以下簡単に触れておきます。(アメリカ合衆国憲法条文及び説明については、U.S. Constitution | @LIICornell で検索できます。)

政策方向性を考えると、上院 Senate に特化された権限では、下記が気になります。
○ 条約批准・修正等に係る大統領への出席議員の3分の2による助言と承認(Article II, Section 2, Clause 2, U.S. Constitution “He shall have Power, by and with the Advice and Consent of the Senate, to make Treaties, provided two thirds of the Senators present concur;”)
○ 公務員任命に係る大統領への助言と承認 (Article II, Section 2, Clause 2, U.S. Constitution “and he shall nominate, and by and with the Advice and Consent of the Senate, shall appoint Ambassadors, other public Ministers and Consuls, Judges of the supreme Court, and all other Officers of the United States, whose Appointments are not herein otherwise provided for, and which shall be established by Law: but the Congress may by Law vest the Appointment of such inferior Officers, as they think proper, in the President alone, in the Courts of Law, or in the Heads of Departments.”)
○ フィリバスター宣言による議事停止(Rule XXII, STANDING RULES OF THE SENATE: REVISED TO JANUARY 24, 2013
今は上記規則上必要無くなった長時間演説は減っているようですが、クルーズ議員のオバマケア反対演説が報道では良くも悪くも大きく取り上げられていました(例. Cruz ends marathon speech | @burgessev @politico)。

他方、下院 House に特化された権限では予算法案の先議権(※ Article I, Section 7, U.S. Constitution)などがありますが、政策方向性を考えるとやはり定数・任期・党派構成などが上院と異なることによる下院の政治動向が気になります。

All bills for raising revenue shall originate in the House of Representatives; but the Senate may propose or concur with amendments as on other Bills.
Every bill which shall have passed the House of Representatives and the Senate, shall, before it become a law, be presented to the President of the United States; if he approve he shall sign it, but if not he shall return it, with his objections to that House in which it shall have originated, who shall enter the objections at large on their journal, and proceed to reconsider it. If after such reconsideration two thirds of that House shall agree to pass the bill, it shall be sent, together with the objections, to the other House, by which it shall likewise be reconsidered, and if approved by two thirds of that House, it shall become a law. But in all such cases the votes of both Houses shall be determined by yeas and nays, and the names of the persons voting for and against the bill shall be entered on the journal of each House respectively. If any bill shall not be returned by the President within ten days (Sundays excepted) after it shall have been presented to him, the same shall be a law, in like manner as if he had signed it, unless the Congress by their adjournment prevent its return, in which case it shall not be a law.
Every order, resolution, or vote to which the concurrence of the Senate and House of Representatives may be necessary (except on a question of adjournment) shall be presented to the President of the United States; and before the same shall take effect, shall be approved by him, or being disapproved by him, shall be repassed by two thirds of the Senate and House of Representatives, according to the rules and limitations prescribed in the case of a bill.

選挙の結果予想は、上院については、2016 Senate Election Interactive Map: 34 U.S. Senate seats to be contested in 2016 | @270toWin (@CookPolitical,@LarrySabato,@battleground_16) では、民主党・共和党いずれが過半数を取るかは予測し切れず、また、現職落選(いずれも共和党)はイリノイ・ニューハンプシャー・ペンシルバニア・ウィスコンシンと予測されています。GOP Hopes Rise In Battle For The Senate, But Democrats Still Have The Edge (11/7) | @JessicaTaylor @nprpolitics では、現職或いはその後継者の党議席維持と予測されているミズーリ・ノースカロライナ・インディアナ・ネバダ・フロリダ・アリゾナ・オハイオについても、上記4州に加えて説明があります。
下院は 2016 House Election Interactive Map: All 435 House seats to be contested in 2016 | @270toWin (@CookPolitical,@LarrySabato,@battleground_16) で共和党が過半数を取ると予測されています。

以上、投票直前の東部標準時8日早朝の一応の概観です。最友好国とは言え外国の選挙なので、どの選挙で誰が当選しても今後も関係を深化させて行くのみでしょう。

“The Creation and Destruction of Value” 価値の創造と破壊 Vol.13

(All the below links are in English.)

Vol.13 パワーポリティクスの重要性(第5章-3)
 経常海外収支の考え方には二つのアプローチがある。第一に、貯蓄と投資のレベルの所産である。貯蓄余剰が経常海外余剰を産み、貯蓄と投資の差額の輸出をもたらす。貯蓄のマイナスは海外からの資本流入で補われる。第二に、投資収入からモノ・サービスへの純支払額を引くという考え方である。
 米国の投資勘定は、長期間の経済政策の転移を示している。1946年には、米国の為替勘定はGDP比3.9%に相当する黒字を計上し、貿易収支は67億ドルの黒字、サービス貿易収支は10億ドルの黒字を計上した。その後の30年間、米国は、全世界に投資を続け、また、西欧と日本の地域経済の構造を変えた。その結果、固定為替制いわゆるブレトンウッズ体制が崩壊した1971年には、総累積で、米国の為替勘定はGDP比0.1%に相当する赤字を計上し、貿易収支は23億ドルの赤字、サービス貿易収支は少し黒字、投資勘定収支は73億ドルの黒字を計上した。更に1985年には、巨大財政赤字と緊縮通貨政策の下で急激な米ドル高となり、為替勘定でGDP比2.8%・1182億ドルの赤字、投資勘定収支は257億ドルの黒字を計上した。借り入れブーム最終期の21世紀初頭には、米国は、政府が拠出しているファニーメイやフレディマックのモーゲージ債への資本流入を大量に得ており、2008年には中国やロシアなどの外国人による購入は累積で1兆3000億ドルを計上した。

あくまで参考
The Current Acccount vs the Trade Deficit | @gregmankiwblog
Current Account Deficits: Is There a Problem? | Atish Ghosh & Uma Ramakrishnan @IMFNews
Financial Globalization and the U.S. Current Account Deficit (PDF) | Matthew Higgins & Thomas Klitgaard @NewYorkFed
The Role of Savings and Investment in Balancing the Current Account: Some Empirical Evidence from the United States (PDF) | Giovanni P. Olivei @BostonFed
Foreign Bondholders – and not the U.S. Mortgage Market – Drove the Fannie/Freddie Bailout | WILLIAM PATALON III @moneymorning
Russia’s Financial Crisis: Economic Setbacks and Policy Responses | @SIPA